There are, with the occasional exception two kinds of economist, Austrian and rubbish. Professor von Hayek was an Austrian. His most famous book was The Road to Serfdom which tells us that central planning cannot get it right because planners cannot anticipate demand. Further, importantly that freedom allows initiative to flourish. When he was awarded Nobel Prize he Explained Economists as dangerous idiots.
Friedrich Hayek ex Wiki
Hayek was a major political thinker of the twentieth century,[4]
and his account of how
changing prices communicate information which enables individuals to
coordinate their plans is widely regarded as an important achievement in
economics.[5]
He also contributed to the fields of
systems thinking,
jurisprudence,
neuroscience, and the
history of ideas.[6] Hayek served in
World War I and said that his experience in the war and his desire to help avoid
the mistakes that had led to the war led him to his career. Hayek lived in
Austria, Great Britain, the United States and Germany, and became a British
subject in 1938. He spent most of his academic life at the
London School of Economics (LSE), the
University of Chicago, and the
University of Freiburg. In 1984, he was appointed as a member of the
Order of the Companions of Honour by Queen
Elizabeth II on the advice of Prime Minister
Margaret Thatcher for his "services to the study of economics".[7]
He was the first recipient of the
Hanns Martin Schleyer Prize in 1984.[8]
He also received the US
Presidential Medal of Freedom in 1991 from president
George H. W. Bush.[9]
In 2011, his article
The Use of Knowledge in Society was selected as one of the top 20
articles published in the
American Economic Review during its first 100 years.[10]
The Road to Serfdom
- available from
Amazon The Road to Serfdom is among the most influential and popular
expositions of market
libertarianism and remains a popular and influential work in contemporary
discourse, selling over two million copies, and remaining a best-seller.[2][3] The Road to Serfdom was to be the popular edition of the second volume
of Hayek’s treatise entitled “The Abuse and Decline of Reason”,[4]
and the title was inspired by the writings of the 19th century French classical
liberal thinker
Alexis de Tocqueville on the “road to servitude”.[5]
The book was first published in Britain by
Routledge
in March 1944, during
World
War II, and was quite popular, leading Hayek to call it “that unobtainable
book”, also due in part to wartime paper rationing.[6]
It was published in the United States by the
University of Chicago Press in September 1944 and achieved great popularity.
At the arrangement of editor
Max
Eastman, the American magazine
Reader's Digest published an abridged version in April 1945, enabling
The Road to Serfdom to reach a wider popular audience beyond academics. The Road to Serfdom has had a significant impact on twentieth-century
conservative and libertarian economic and political discourse, and is often
cited today by commentators. But when economic power is centralized as an instrument of
political power it creates a degree of dependence scarcely
distinguishable from slavery. It has been well said that, in a
country where the sole employer is the state, opposition means death
by slow starvation. The book was originally published for a British audience by Routledge Press
in March 1944 in the United Kingdom and then by the
University of Chicago Press in September 1944. The U.S. publisher’s
expectation was that the book would sell between 900 and 3,000 copies. The
initial printing run of 2,000 copies was quickly sold out, and 30,000 copies
were sold within six months. In 2007, the University of Chicago Press estimated
that more than 350,000 copies had been sold.[8] A 20 page version of the book was then published in the April 1945 issue of
Reader's Digest,[9]
with a press run of several million copies. A 95 page abridged version was also
published in 1945 and 1946.[10]
In February 1945 a picture-book version[11]
was published in
Look magazine, later made into a
pamphlet
and distributed by
General Motors. The book has been translated into approximately 20 languages
and is dedicated to “The
socialists
of all
parties”. The introduction to the 50th anniversary edition is written by
Milton Friedman (another recipient of the
Nobel Prize in Economics 1976). In 2007, the
University of Chicago Press issued a “Definitive Edition”, Volume 2 in the
“Collected Works of F. A. Hayek” series. In June 2010, the book achieved new
popularity by rising to the top of the
Amazon.com
bestseller list following extended coverage of the book on
The Glenn Beck Program. Since that date, it has sold another 250,000
copies in its print and digital editions. Summary Centralized planning is inherently undemocratic in Hayek's view, because it
requires "that the will of a small minority be imposed upon the people".[16]
The power of these minorities to act by taking money or property in pursuit of
centralized goals, destroys the Rule of Law and individual freedoms.[17]
Where there is centralized planning, "the individual would more than ever become
a mere means, to be used by the authority in the service of such abstractions as
the 'social welfare' or the 'good of the community'".[18]
Even the very poor have more personal freedom in an open society than a
centrally planned one.[19]
"[W]hile the last resort of a competitive economy is the
bailiff, the
ultimate sanction of a planned economy is the hangman."[20]
Socialism is a hypocritical system, because its professed humanitarian goals can
only be put into practice by brutal methods "of which most socialists
disapprove".[21]
Such centralized systems also require effective propaganda, so that the people
come to believe that the state's goals are theirs.[22] Hayek argues that the roots of Nazism lie in socialism,[23]
and then draws parallels to the thought of British leaders: The increasing veneration for the state, the admiration of power, and of
bigness for bigness' sake, the enthusiasm for "organization" of everything
(we now call it "planning") and that "inability to leave anything to the
simple power of organic growth"...are all scarcely less marked in England
now than they were in Germany.[24] Hayek believed that after World War II, "wisdom in the management of our
economic affairs will be even more important than before and that the fate of
our civilization will ultimately depend on how we solve the economic problems we
shall then face".[25]
The only chance to build a decent world is "to improve the general level of
wealth" via the activities of free markets.[26]
He saw international organization as involving a further threat to individual
freedom.[27]
He concluded: "The guiding principle that a policy of freedom for the individual
is the only truly progressive policy remains as true today as it was in the
nineteenth century."[28] A role for government
The successful use of competition as the principle of social organization
precludes certain types of coercive interference with economic life, but it
admits of others which sometimes may very considerably assist its work and
even requires certain kinds of government action.[29] While Hayek is opposed to regulations which restrict the freedom to enter a
trade, or to buy and sell at any price, or to control quantities, he
acknowledges the utility of regulations which restrict allowed methods of
production, so long as these are applied equally to everyone and not used as an
indirect way of controlling prices or quantities, and without forgetting the
cost of such restrictions: To prohibit the use of certain poisonous substances, or to require
special precautions in their use, to limit working hours or to require
certain sanitary arrangements, is fully compatible with the preservation of
competition. The only question here is whether in the particular instance
the advantages gained are greater than the social costs which they impose.[30] He notes that there are certain areas, such as the environment, where
activities which cause damage to third parties (known to economists as "negative
externalities") cannot effectively be regulated solely by the marketplace: Nor can certain harmful effects of deforestation, of some methods of
farming, or of the smoke and noise of factories, be confined to the owner of
the property in question, or to those who are willing to submit to the
damage for an agreed compensation.[31] The government also has a role in preventing fraud: Even the most essential prerequisite of its [the market's] proper
functioning, the prevention of fraud and deception (including exploitation
of ignorance), provides a great and by no means fully accomplished object of
legislative activity.[32] The government also has a role in creating a safety net: There is no reason why, in a society which has reached the general level
of wealth ours has, the first kind of security should not be guaranteed to
all without endangering general freedom; that is: some minimum of food,
shelter and clothing, sufficient to preserve health. Nor is there any reason
why the state should not help to organize a comprehensive system of social
insurance in providing for those common hazards of life against which few
can make adequate provision.[33][34] He concludes: "In no system that could be rationally defended would the state
just do nothing."[32]
Contemporary
commentary
George Orwell responded with both praise and criticism, stating, "in the
negative part of Professor Hayek's thesis there is a great deal of truth. It
cannot be said too often – at any rate, it is not being said nearly often enough
– that collectivism is not inherently democratic, but, on the contrary, gives to
a tyrannical minority such powers as the Spanish Inquisitors never dreamt of."
Yet he also warned, "[A] return to 'free' competition means for the great mass
of people a tyranny probably worse, because more irresponsible, than that of the
state."[37] Hayek's work was influential enough to warrant mention during the
1945 British general election, when according to
Harold Macmillan,
Winston Churchill was "fortified in his apprehensions [of a
Labour government] by reading Professor Hayek's The Road to Serfdom"[38]
when he warned in an election broadcast in 1945 that a socialist system would
"have to fall back on some form of
Gestapo".
The Labour leader
Clement Attlee responded in his election broadcast by claiming that what
Churchill had said was the "second-hand version of the academic views of an
Austrian professor, Friedrich August von Hayek".[39]
The
Conservative Central Office sacrificed 1.5 tons of their precious paper
ration allocated for the 1945 election so that more copies of The Road to
Serfdom could be printed, although to no avail, as Labour won a landslide
victory.[40] The Road to Serfdom was placed fourth on the list of the 100 best
non-fiction books of the twentieth century[41]
compiled by
National Review magazine. It also made #16 in reader selections
of the hundred best non-fiction book of the twentieth century administered by
Modern Library.[42] The Road to Serfdom appears on
Martin Seymour-Smith's list of the
100 Most Influential Books Ever Written, whilst it made #1 on
Human Events: Top Ten Books Every Republican Congressman Should Read[43]
in 2006. Milton Friedman's assessment: I think the Adam Smith role was played in this cycle [i.e. the late
twentieth century collapse of socialism in which the idea of free-markets
succeeded first, and then special events catalyzed a complete change of
socio-political policy in countries around the world] by Friedrich Hayek’s
The Road to Serfdom.[44]
Alan Brinkley's assessment: The publication of two books...helped to galvanize the concerns that were
beginning to emerge among intellectuals (and many others) about the
implications of totalitarianism. One was James Burnham’s The Managerial
Revolution.. [A second] Friedrich A. Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom..
was far more controversial – and influential. Even more than Burnham, Hayek
forced into public discourse the question of the compatibility of democracy
and statism... In responding to Burnham and Hayek...liberals [in the statist
sense of this term as used by some in the United States] were in fact
responding to a powerful strain of Jeffersonian anti-statism in American
political culture... The result was a subtle but important shift in liberal
[i.e. American statist] thinking.[44]
Herman Finer, a
Fabian socialist, published a rebuttal in his The Road to Reaction in
1946. Hayek called Finer's book "a specimen of abuse and invective which is
probably unique in contemporary academic discussion".[46]
Barbara Wootton wrote Freedom under Planning[47]
after reading an early copy of The Road to Serfdom, provided to her by
Hayek. In the introduction to her book, Wootton mentioned The Road to Serfdom
and claimed that "Much of what I have written is devoted to criticism of the
views put forward by Professor Hayek in this and other books."[48]
The central argument made in Freedom under Planning is that "there is
nothing in the conscious planning of economic priorities which is inherently
incompatible with the freedoms which mean most to the contemporary Englishman or
American. Civil liberties are quite unaffected. We can, if we wish, deliberately
plan so as to give the fullest possible scope for the pursuit by individuals and
social groups of cultural ends which are in no way state-determined."[49]
Wootton criticizes Hayek for claiming that planning must lead to
oppression, when, in her view, that is merely one possibility among many.
She argues that "there seems hardly better case for taking for granted that
planning will bring the worst to the top than for the opposite assumption that
the seats of office will be filled with angels".[50]
Thus, Wootton acknowledges the possibility that planning may exist alongside
tyranny, but claims that it is equally possible to combine planning with
freedom. She concludes that "A happy and fruitful marriage between freedom and
planning can, in short, be arranged."[51] However,
Frank
Knight, founder of the
Chicago School of Economics, disputes the claim that Freedom under
Planning contradicts The Road to Serfdom. He wrote in a scholarly
review of the Wootton book: "Let me repeat that the Wootton book is in no
logical sense an answer to The Road to Serfdom, whatever may be thought
of the cogency of Hayek's argument, or the soundness of his position."[52] In his review (collected in The Present as History, 1953)
Marxist
Paul
Sweezy joked that Hayek would have you believe that if there was an
over-production of baby carriages, the central planners would then order the
population to have more babies instead of simply warehousing the temporary
excess of carriages and decreasing production for next year. The
cybernetic arguments of
Stafford Beer in his 1974 CBC Massey Lectures, Designing Freedom –
that intelligent adaptive planning can increase freedom – are of interest in
this regard, as is the technical work of
Herbert A. Simon and
Albert
Ando on the dynamics of hierarchical nearly decomposable systems in
economics – namely, that everything in such a system is not tightly coupled to
everything else.[53]
Jeffrey Sachs wrote that the social-welfare states, with high rates of
taxation and social outlays, outperform the relatively free-market economies,
according to the
empirical evidence.[54]
William Easterly wrote a rebuttal[55]
and Sachs wrote a re-rebuttal.[56] Eric
Zencey wrote that the free market economy Hayek advocated is designed for an
infinite planet, and when it runs into physical limits (as any growing system
must), the result is a need for centralized planning to mediate the problematic
interface of economy and nature. "Planning is planning, whether it's done to
minimize poverty and injustice, as socialists were advocating then, or to
preserve the minimum flow of ecosystem services that civilization requires, as
we are finding increasingly necessary today."[57] Mises Institute
libertarian/anarcho-capitalist
economist
Walter
Block has observed critically that while The Road to Serfdom makes a
strong case against centrally planned economies, it appears only lukewarm in its
support of a
free
market system and
laissez-faire
capitalism,
with Hayek even going so far as to say that "probably nothing has done so much
harm to the liberal cause as the wooden insistence of some liberals on certain
rules of thumb, above all the principle of laissez-faire capitalism". In the
book, Hayek writes that the government has a role to play in the economy through
the monetary system (a view that he later withdrew),[58]
work-hours regulation, social welfare, and institutions for the flow of proper
information. Through analysis of this and many other of Hayek's works, Block
asserts that: "in making the case against socialism, Hayek was led into making
all sort of compromises with what otherwise appeared to be his own philosophical
perspective – so much so, that if a system was erected on the basis of them, it
would not differ too sharply from what this author explicitly opposed".[59]
Gordon Tullock has argued Hayek's analysis predicted totalitarian
governments in much of Europe in the late 20th century. He uses Sweden, in which
the government at that time controlled 63 percent of
GNP,
as an example to support his argument that the basic problem with The Road to
Serfdom is "that it offered predictions which turned out to be false. The
steady advance of government in places such as Sweden has not led to any loss of
non-economic freedoms." While criticizing Hayek, Tullock still praises the
classical liberal notion of economic freedom, saying, "Arguments for political
freedom are strong, as are the arguments for economic freedom. We needn’t make
one set of arguments depend on the other."[60]
However, according to
Robert Skidelsky, Hayek "safeguarded himself from such retrospective
refutation". Skidelsky argues that Hayek's argument was contingent, and that,
"By the 1970s there was some evidence of the slippery slope…and then there was
Thatcher. Hayek's warning played a critical part in her determination to
'roll back the state.'"[61]
QUOTE
Friedrich August Hayek
CH (8 May 1899 – 23 March 1992), born in
Austria-Hungary as Friedrich August von Hayek and frequently known as
F. A. Hayek, was an Austrian, later British,[1]
economist[2]
and
philosopher best known for his defense of
classical liberalism. In 1974, Hayek shared the
Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (with
Gunnar Myrdal) for his "pioneering work in the
theory of money and
economic fluctuations and ... penetrating analysis of the interdependence of
economic, social and institutional phenomena".[3]
UNQUOTE
A good bloke.
QUOTE
The Road to Serfdom is a book written by the Austrian-born
economist
and
philosopher
Friedrich von Hayek (1899–1992) between 1940–1943, in which he "warned of
the danger of
tyranny that inevitably results from government control of economic
decision-making through
central planning",[1]
and in which he argues that the abandonment of
individualism and
classical liberalism inevitably leads to a loss of
freedom, the
creation of an oppressive society, the tyranny of a
dictator
and the serfdom
of the individual. Significantly, Hayek challenged the general view among
British academics that
fascism was
a
capitalist reaction against socialism, instead arguing that fascism and
socialism had common roots in central economic planning and the power of the
state over the individual.Publication
Hayek argues that Western democracies, including the United Kingdom and the
United States, have “progressively abandoned that freedom in economic affairs
without which personal and political freedom has never existed in the past”.[12]
Society has mistakenly tried to ensure continuing prosperity by centralized
planning, which inevitably leads to totalitarianism. “We have in effect
undertaken to dispense with the forces which produced unforeseen results and to
replace the impersonal and anonymous mechanism of the market by collective and
‘conscious’ direction of all social forces to deliberately chosen goals.”[13]
Socialism, while presented as a means of assuring equality, does so through
“restraint and servitude”, while “democracy seeks equality in liberty”.[14]
Planning, because coercive, is an inferior method of regulation, while the
competition of a free market is superior “because it is the only method by which
our activities can be adjusted to each other without coercive or arbitrary
intervention of authority”.[15]
Although Hayek believed that government intervention in markets would lead to
a loss of freedom, he recognized a limited role for government to perform tasks
of which free markets were not capable:
John Maynard Keynes said of it: "In my opinion it is a grand book...Morally
and philosophically I find myself in agreement with virtually the whole of it:
and not only in agreement with it, but in deeply moved agreement."[35]
Having said that, Keynes did not think Hayek's philosophy was of practical
use; this was explained later in the same letter, commenting: "What we need
therefore, in my opinion, is not a change in our economic programmes, which
would only lead in practice to disillusion with the results of your philosophy;
but perhaps even the contrary, namely, an enlargement of them. Your greatest
danger is the probable practical failure of the application of your philosophy
in the United States."[36]
Criticism
The Road To Serfdom has been criticized on theoretical grounds.
Economic sociologist
Karl
Polanyi made a case diametrically opposed to Hayek, arguing that unfettered
markets had undermined the social order and that economic breakdown had paved
the way for the emergence of dictatorship.[45]
Libertarian/Conservative critics
UNQUOTE
He set Maggie on the right road.